CLASSICAL LIBERALISM AND FREEDOM OF THE PRESS

By: Leonard P. Liggio

Histories of the Classical Liberal tradition begin with the Stoic philosophers of the Greco-Roman world. Greek political philosophy of Plato and Aristotle focused on the polis or Greek city-state with its small and homogeneous population. This world ended with Alexander the Great’s conquest of the Persian Empire. With his early death, his generals who were his successors from Egypt and Greece to the Indus River established several empires with large new cities of many populations but with commercial Greek as the common language. The polis was replaced by the cosmos polis – the world city, or the whole world as a single country, cosmopolitan. The Stoic philosophers took the world city as their starting point, that is, a world without distinctions of family origins. Civilized people spoke Greek, but non-Greek speakers were equally part of mankind.

Although people might speak Greek they came from different countries with different legal systems. The Romans who were very conservative about treasuring their archaic legal system realized that all the merchants who came to Rome had better commercial concepts. The Roman Republic set up a separate judgeship for the foreign merchants which drew on all the different commercial legal concepts to formulate the most efficient and productive law merchant. The Romans generalized from this and felt that what was common to various law systems indicated a common source of law – a natural law. Cicero’s legal writings represented this Stoic philosophy of natural law. This was adopted by the Christian philosophers making it the center of Western European thought, and the foundation for Classical Liberalism.

F. A. Hayek, 1974 Nobel Laureate in Economics, is considered the leading classical liberal thinker of the 20th century. His approach might be similar to the Roman jurists. Hayek thought that means which provide happiness and prosperity will be recognized and adopted under freedom, while those which do not will be rejected or lead to failure. He believed that social evolution produces successful social mechanisms while the unsuccessful will die out. Hayek, his mentor, Ludwig von Mises, and his London School of Economics colleagues, Lord Lionel Robbins or Sir Arnold Plant, or his Chicago colleagues, Milton Friedman, George Stigler or Allen Wallis shared the general approach which Hayek best articulated. Of course, as economists, they were operating only in a positivist and utilitarian framework.

However, there are a number of Classical Liberal scholars who believe, like the Stoics, that it is possible to draw a more general philosophical framework from the nature of humankind. Henry Babcock Veatch was the dean of such philosophers. Fred Miller, director of the Social Philosophy and Policy Center at Bowling Green State University, Ohio, Doug Rasmussen, Doug Den Uyl, and Tibor Machan are among these Classical Liberal moral philosophers. A major figure was the late Economics Professor Murray N. Rothbard who felt economics was totally true but incomplete. In addition to Man, Economy and State, and Power and Market, Rothbard wrote The Ethics of Liberty.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio, page 2

These scholars are located in the central tradition of Western philosophy established when Aristotle was brought to the University of Paris from the commentaries of the Arabic philosophers. From Thomas Aquinas to Henry Veatch, natural rights has been at the core of moral philosophy and of classical liberalism. Lord Acton named Thomas Aquinas as the first Whig.

The medieval universities arose in and with the re-emergence of European towns. The towns were the centers of trade and manufacture and sought to protect their developing prosperity from the extortion of taxation. There was a struggle for autonomy which resulted in most towns gaining charters which protected their resources through self-government. There was a pamphlet literature at each stage of struggles for autonomy which provides early contributions to political philosophy. The defense of representative institutions against centralizing power provided part of the Classical Liberal legacy.

This defense became more developed as the Reformation Age saw the emergence of absolute rulers who removed constrains by the representative institutions in which diverse religious opinions found expression and protection. England, the Netherlands and Switzerland were the countries in which the executive powers were limited and the representative institutions were able to be maintained. The taxing power was kept in the hands of the representative institutions and thus taxes were low in these countries.

The 17th and 18th centuries were the ones in which English liberties flourish: one monarch was executed, a second went into exile, a republic had been instituted, the Bill of Rights became the constitutional foundation, the house of commons flourished after German monarchs were installed who preferred to remain in Hannover, France, meanwhile, was spared most of this healthy struggle; in 1614 was the last meeting of the Estates General. The next meeting was one hundred and seventy-five years later when the fiscal crisis of the national debt caused the recall of the Estates General in 1789. That in a nut-shell would be traditional Whig history.

Elizabeth I’s forty-five year reign was one of autumnal warmth. Taxes were kept low.

There were practically no central government agents around the country. Unlike continental Europe with extensive tax collecting systems and huge bureaucracies to find and hold the taxes, England blissfully invested in farms and sheep ranches, metallurgy and textiles, imports and exports, coastal and overseas trade. France had ten times the number of government officials per person as did England. It would be hard to say which was more beneficial to England, the low taxes or the absence of government inspectors to interfere with productive economic activities. The low taxes meant there was capital to invest in the variety of initiatives available because there were no bureaucrats to prevent enterprise.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 3

This was challenged with the succession to Elizabeth of her nephew, James VI of Scotland, James I of England, son of Mary, Queen of Scots (executed by Elizabeth). In Scotland, James was raised in the theory, if not the practice, of absolute monarchy. Not the least he wished the revenues which continental absolute monarchies could gather. When he could not get tax increases, he would issue grants of monopolies. The grantees of the courtiers would pay up-front and then collect from the consumers who bought their monopolized product.

The parliament in 1601 had condemned the issuing of monopolies as against Magna Charta. Parliament strongly declared monopolies contrary to the ancient and fundamental laws of the realm, and utterly void in 1624. The king forbade parliament to “meddle with the mysteries of state,” and he tore out the offending pages of the Journal of the Commons, dissolved parliament, and sent former chief justice Sir Edward Coke and other leaders of Commons to the Tower of London.

Charles I became king in March, 1625, and dissolved two parliaments in the first fifteen months of his reign. In 1628 a third parliament proposed the Petition of Right drawn up by Sir Edward Coke. It denounced illegal taxation, arbitrary imprisonment, billeting of soldiers in homes, and martial law. Charles I dissolved parliament and sought to rule for eleven years without calling parliament and tried to operate on existing taxation. Just as fifteen years earlier the French crown had closed the last Estates General for one hundred and seventy-five years, Charles might have achieved the same goal.  Many in England expected that conclusion; some chose to immigrate and the Great Migration to New England began in 1629.

Charles recalled parliament, and it resolved not to be dissolved – the Long Parliament. Parliament defeated and beheaded Charles I. The Commonwealth under Lord Protector Oliver Cromwell meant the maintenance of a large standing army, and thus, heavy taxes. After Cromwell’s death the Long Parliament returned to recall Charles II from exile. Charles II did not wish to resume that journey abroad and so tried to minimize exactions.

The 17th Century English political conflict, in particular, is the starting point for modern journalism, and freedom of the press is central to Classical Liberalism. Classical Liberalism’s concept is captured best by one of its greatest doyens, Thomas Jefferson: “if one must have a society with government and no newspapers, or with newspapers and no government, only the latter is desirable.”

The printing press during the later 15th Century created one of the great revolutions in world history. With the wide distribution of classic and modern works, printing made a major contribution to the religious revivals of the Protestant Reformation and the Catholic Reformation. Small devotional tracts or critiques of others’ theology could be spread widely. Authors began to publish Annual Registers of foreign and domestic news. Finally, there appeared one page weekly or semi-weekly reports of foreign news. Current foreign or domestic news were considered to “Meddle with the mysteries of state.” Thus, they were of concerned to rulers and those close to rulers alone.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 4

In London in 1619 there began to appear A Relation of all matters done in Bohemia, Austria, Poland, etc. and in 1621 The certain and true news from all parts of Germany and Poland.  Finally, in 1622 and onwards, The Weekly Newes from Italy, Germany, etc.  and a rival, Newes from Most Parts of Christendom.  The possible demand for current information may have been the event which began the Thirty-Years War (1618-1648):

James I’s daughter was married to the Count Palatine of the Rhine (the Palatinate) who was elected king of Bohemia against the claim of the Habsburg Emperor. One early effect of preparation for war was the change of the price of grain in Danzig (the benchmark price for centuries) as England and Western Europe drew much of their grain from Poland via the Baltic.

In France, Cardinal Richelieu in 1631 granted a monopoly to the Gazette de France, and often wrote the foreign news himself, with an occasional article by Louis XIII.

With no intention of ever calling parliament, Charles I preferred control over foreign news. The non-common law, prerogative Court of Star Chamber in 1632 issued an edict forbidding printing of foreign news. However, Star Chamber was abolished by the

Parliamentary Revolution in 1641, and free printing of newspapers began, especially that the parliamentary and royal sides wish to influence public opinion. The heavy publishing of royalist and parliamentary pamphlets was more than matched by the printing of religious literature. The staid studies by Anglican and Puritan divines was overwhelmed by the writings of Independent church’s students of the Bible. A large number of persons felt that they had discovered the long hidden codes to interpreting the Bible and rush into print with their views. Once the parliamentary party executed the king, the government sought to control the press, and only have an official government newspaper.

Among the many political positions advocated during the English Civil War, the most significant was the Levellers. The Levellers advocated a republic and equality before the law rather than special privileges. The Levellers were strongly represented in the parliamentary army from which they presented to the parliamentary commander, Lord Fairfax, The Case of the Army truly stated, in October, 1647. It was presented by John Lillburne, and demanded that the parliament be subordinate to a paramount constitution.

The Agreement of the People was presented to Cromwell, Ireton and other generals by James Wildman, Thomas Rainsborough and Edward Saxby for the Levellers. After the beheading of Charles I in January, 1649, Lilburne’s England’s New Chains sought the end of Cromwell’s Council of State and for parliamentary elections. When he continued with Second Part of England’s New Chains, Lilburne, Richard Overton, and William Walwyn were arrested in March, 1649. Levellers in the parliamentary army challenged the order to invade Ireland, but were suppressed by Cromwell and were sent to Ireland.

The Levellers’ color, sea green, became a distinguishing mark of the Whigs.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 5

John Milton is a major Classical Liberal, especially for contributing to freedom of the press. Against Parliament’s censorship and licensing ordinance of June, 1643, Milton wrote his renowned Areopatitica, a Speech of Mr. John Milton for the Liberty of Unlicensed Printing, to the Parliament of England (November 25, 1644). Milton’s work was unlicensed and unregistered. Despite official appeals to Parliament, Milton was not prosecuted and the ordinance was unenforced. Milton became Cromwell’s Latin (foreign) secretary, and publisher of the government’s twice weekly newspaper.

The Restored Monarchy in 1660 established a friendly press. It enacted the Licensing Act of 1662 which required all publications be submitted to the Stationers’Company and censorship by civil and ecclesiastical authorities.

On the death of Charles II, his brother, James, Duke of York, became king in 1685. James II was an open Catholic and less careful than his late brother. Opposition invited James daughter, Mary and her husband, William of Orange, ruler of The Netherlands to replace him. James went into exile in France in November, 1688 – The Glorious Revolution of 1688. John Locke returned from exile in The Netherlands in 1689. John Locke was a member of a small group of Whig parliamentarians, called the ‘College’, the leader of which was Lord Somers (1651-1716), Lord Keeper and then Lord Chancellor. The parliament passed the Bill of Rights in 1689, and provided for regular elections and meetings of parliament, leading to the central role of the House of Commons. As the Licensing Act was expiring in 1695 Locke and the ‘College’ focused on press freedom:

“Various questions were now raised. Was prevention better than punishment? Could the state rely upon the law courts rather than the censor? Opinion was mixed. William, mindful of the free Dutch press, was inclined to be liberal, but some of his aides argued that it was as much the duty of the state to be forehanded in restraining the perpetuation of libels as other crimes.

“Somers is said to have been convinced that the regulations were not only vexatious, but ineffective, and to have pointed out that, since the Revolution, the press had poured forth more libellous works, affecting both the government and private individuals, than in any former age. We know that he was connected with the ‘College’, a group of politicians associated with John Locke, and there is ample evidence of the part played by this association in bringing in a bill designed as an alternative for the expiring Act. … In the end the Commons, apparently motivated largely by opposition to the monopoly of the Stationers’ Company, would neither enact new legislation nor renew the old. Freedom of the press was, to some extent, advanced by default.” (William L. Sachse, Lord Somers, A Political Portrait (Manchester, England, Manchester University Press and Madison, Wisc.

University of Wisconsin Press, 1975, pp. 98-99.)

The Glorious Revolution of 1688 relaxed press censorship, and when press laws were not renewed in 1695, several newspapers emerged. In 1696, Edward Lloyd, at whose coffee house on Lombard Street maritime insurers meet, published a newspaper, which after suspension was revived with shipping news. The party conflicts between Whigs and Tories led to newspapers subsidized by each side and edited by great essayists of the day.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 6

Daniel Defoe, Richard Steele and Joseph Addison tended to be Whigs. Jonathan Swift developed the editorial for the Tory press before receiving preference as dean of St. Patrick’s Cathedral, Dublin. The most important contributions were the newspaper letters

(1720s) of John Trenchard and Thomas Gordon (Cato’s Letter, Essays on Liberty, edited and annotated by Ronald Hamowy ( 2 volumes) Indianapolis, IN, Liberty Press, 1995). Trenchard and Gordon concealed their identities by using the hero of the opposition to Julius Caesar, Cato the Younger (95-46 B. C.) who championed Stoicism, liberty and republican principles as the last commander against Caesar at Utica in North Africa. Cato’s Letters are considered the most read essays contributing to the American Revolution and the dissemination of John Locke’s ideas. Lord Bollingbroke’s opposition newspaper, the Craftsman, in the 1730s, and Samuel Johnson’s the Rambler (from 1750) and the Idler (from 1758) were also milestones.

The popularity of newspapers, led in 1712, to the imposing of a Stamp Tax. Some of the great contributions to literature had to close while the sensational press could afford the tax. The ‘taxes on knowledge’ continued as a source of government revenue. It was leaders of Classical Liberalism, such as Richard Cobden, who took the lead in moving the reduction, and finally, abolition of press taxes in 1855 and duties on newsprint in 1861.

The dramatic political conflicts in England between crown and parliament led to great political writing. A strong supporter of the crown in his Leviathan was Thomas Hobbes.

Hobbes greatest opponent was the Classical Liberal, John Locke. Locke took as hisfoil Sir Robert Filmer’s Patriarcha which defended absolute government against the Classical Liberal contract theory presented by the Jesuit Cardinal, Robert Bellarmine. John Locke’s Two Treatises on Civil Government is the foundation stone of Classical Liberal political philosophy. It was the keystone of the philosophy of the American Founding Fathers.

The distinguished historian of political thought, George H. Sabine, said of Locke’s

Second Treatise:

it reached back into the past,right across the whole period of the civil wars,

and joined hands with Hooker’s Ecclesiastical Polity, which had summed up

the political thought of England at the close of the Reformation and before the

break between parliament and the king. Through Hooker Locke was joined with

the long tradition of medieval political thought back to St. Thomas, in which the

reality of moral restraints on power, the responsibility of rulers to the communities

which they ruled, and the subordination of government to law were axiomatic. …

The medieval tradition, which Locke tapped through Hooker, was an indispensable part of the constitutional ideals of the Revolution of 1688. The years of the civil wars had changed but had not destroyed it. Locke’s problem, therefore, was not to reproduce historically the thought of Hooker but to gather together anew the abiding elements of that thought and to restate them in the light of what had happened in the intervening century. (A History of Political Theory, New York, Henry Holt, 1953.)

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 7

John Locke, like Richard Hooker a century earlier, was building on the important 16th and 17th century political theorists. Of greatest importance was the work of the Dutchman, Hugo Grotius. Today we have a better sense of the foundations on which Grotius built, especially the Iberian Scholastic moral philosophers. At the beginning was the friar and bishop of Chiapas, Bartolome de las Casas, who strongly defended the humanity and human rights of the American Indians. (The best works on the subject are by Lewis Hanke, All Mankind is One (Dekalb, IL, Northern Illinois University Press, 1974); and his Aristotle and the American Indians: A Study of Race Prejudice in the Modern World (Bloomington, IN, Indiana University Press, 1970).

As George Sabine noted: in the development of modern constitutionalism and international law, “behind Grotius was the systematic jurisprudence of the Spaniards” (p. 391). Of the many Spanish Scholastics of note, we might mention Francisco de Vitoria (1480-1546), Luis de Molina (1535-1601), Juan de Mariana (1536-1624), and Francisco Suarez (1548-1617). Additionally, the Spanish Scholastics made original contributions to modern economics. They presented an advanced understanding of the market and the harmful impact of regulation and taxation. F. A. Hayek highlighted their contribution to economics, and encouraged the publications of his former student, Professor Marjorie Grice-Hutchinson (The School of Salamanca (Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1952). (Cf. Alejandro A. Chafuen, Christians for Freedom: Late Scholastic Economics ( with a foreword by Michael Novak, San Francisco, Ignatius Press, 1986); and Murray N. Rothbard, Classical Economics, volume I (Brookfield, VT, Edward Elgar, 1995.)

Locke’s political philosophy gained the adherence of the French thinkers or philosophes whom we associate with the Enlightenment. Locke’s Europe-wide impact was a major step toward solidifying Classical Liberalism as the best grounded political philosophy.

The Scientific Revolution of the late 17th century, of whom Isaac Newton was the most renowned, challenged thinkers to new levels of accomplishment. Voltaire was one of the French thinkers who wished to bring the ideas of Newton and Locke to his countrymen. Voltaire took refuge in England (1726-1729) from persecution for his writings. He responded with high praise for England’s social, economic and constitutional system in the Philosophical Letters on the English (1734). He saw that the limited government of England not only gave wide breath to scientific discovery and literary composition, but to economic progress and prosperity. One of the best known contributions of Voltaire’s writings was his celebrated report on the London stock exchange. Voltaire declared:

Enter the London stock exchange, that place more respectable than

many a court. You will see the deputies of all nations gathered there

for the service of mankind. There the Jew, the Mohammedan, and

the Christian deal with each other as if they were of the same religion,

and give the name of infidel only to those who go bankrupt; there, the

Presbyterian trusts the Anabaptist, and the Anglican accepts the Quaker’s

promise. On leaving these peaceful and free assemblies, some go to the

synagogue, others go to drink; this one goes to have himself baptized in

the name of the Father, through the Son, to the Holy Ghost; that one has

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 8

his son’s foreskin cut off and Hebrew words mumbled over the child which

he does not understand; others go to their church to await the inspiration of

God, their hats on their heads, and all are content. (VIe Lettre, I, 74)

Voltaire expressed his admiration for ordinary life and for the benignity of business. He had doubts regarding ritual, but saw the culmination of civilization in contentment. Peter Gay has said of Voltaire’s English Letters that they provide “a positive vision of a civilization that assimilates, protects, and profits from a variety of citizens. A sound civilization … is unity in multiplicity; since its virtues and vices constantly act upon each other, the strength of one institution is the strength of all.. The rule of law, commercial prosperity, religious toleration, the flourishing of arts and sciences, civil liberties – all are necessary, all sustain each other.”  (Voltaire’s Politics,  New York, Vintage Books, 1965)

Voltaire was particularly impressed by the role of diversity in the economic prosperity and political stability of England. A variety of religious persuasions co-existed in England. The French Protestants, driven into exile decades earlier by the French state, found successful refuge in England, as a century later, French Catholics, especially clergy and nuns, found warm welcome in England when driven out by the French state. Many English in 1686 or 1791 may not have been pleased with the newcomers; but that did not prevent other English from acting with superb kindness to the refugees and permitting them to enter into normal relations with those who so wished. No one was required to like them, and no one was prohibited from helping them. It was the open society, the freedom of choice, that benefited all.

One of the themes of contemporary History of Ideas is the relationship of commerce to the shift from hostility, cruelty and warfare to conciliation, manners and peace. Peace and Commerce is the motto of Classical Liberalism. A sub-theme is the role of religion in the development of the commercial mentality. The encouragement and expansion of the commercial mind was considered very important by the Classical Liberals.

In the early 18th century, the Baron de Montesquieu, president of the parlement (court) of Bordeaux, visited England, and eventually published (1748) his discussion of the constitution of England in The Spirit of the Laws. Montesquieu had a great admiration for England and the English constitution, and emphasized the central importance of commerce for improving the morals and the customs of societies. Commerce was the defining characteristic of civilization and civilized human beings. In this he was echoed by the great Classical Liberal of early 19th century France, Benjamin Constant.

How did commerce gain such a commanding lead in England? asked Montesquieu. (We are reminded of Napoleon’s sarcastic dismissal of the English in his rivalry with them. He called the English a nation of shopkeepers. For Voltaire and Montesquieu that had been the height of praise.) Montesquieu caught the difference between France and England.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 9

England hardly had any government institutions: it had low taxes and no bureaucrats. The Crown, the Parliament and the judiciary were independent and mutually balanced each other, providing limits on the growth of government. Thus, society was free to breath, to blossom and to prosper.

The period of English history which Voltaire and Montesquieu encountered is called the Whig Supremacy. The Whig party, in some cases the same men, ran the government from 1720 to 1760. As with the press laws at the time of Milton, the parliament did not repeal intrusive laws, they merely were not enforced. Edmund Burke praised it as the period of Salutary Neglect. The government failed to enforce the regulations on the books, and the people of England and its colonies became prosperous. Salutary Neglect permitted English consumers access to cheaper necessities which created a demand for more cheaper necessities. Low taxes allowed the accumulated resources to be invested in new technologies which would further increased the amount and lower the prices for consumers. (Cf.  Neil McKendrick, John Brewer, and J. H. Plumb, The Birth of the Consumer Society: The Commercialization of 18th century England (Bloomington, IN, Indiana University Press, 1982).)

Salutary Neglect began to end when a new, young king succeeded to the throne in 1760, George III. Edmund Burke became the leader of a new Whig party to seek to stop George III and the King’s Friends from destroying the accomplishments of Salutary Neglect. Burke was a friend and admirer of Adam Smith and emphasized economic analysis in the Classical Liberalism of the new Whig party.

Edmund Burke’s Salutary Neglect was phrased in his critique of what the return to government regulation and increased taxes was doing to undermine England’s relations with its North American colonies. Burke was the London agent for the legislature of the New York colony. He saw regulation of the colonies as destructive as regulation in England. Indeed, he saw the regulations and taxes as doubly destructive as they undermined the trade between the English and the Americans.

David Hume, Adam Smith, Adam Ferguson, Edmund Burke were philosophers. They were essentially moralists, writers on moral philosophy. But, they saw that the issues of manners, courtesy, kindness, and peace were rooted in economic life experiences. They saw that no one engaged in commerce belittles or mistreats his customer. Thus, moral philosophers began to become interested in economics. David Hume and Adam Smith are the most famous of moral philosophers who made crucial contributions to the development of economics.

The Scottish Enlightenment of the 18th century was one of the most fruitful parts of the Classical Liberal tradition. Scotland had become part of England in 1707 by the Act of Union. Thus, Scotland was represented in the English parliament, but also was economically integrated into England’s commercial system. Scotland began to become a major entrepreneurial part of the English manufacturing and commercial system.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 10

The Scottish universities flourished while Oxford and Cambridge were somnolent. However, the Scottish universities were not open enough to allow David Hume to teach there; he remained librarian of the Advocates Library.

The Scottish Enlightenment has been the subject of the special interest of F. A. Hayek. As a more purposeful and focused part of the English Enlightenment, they are distinguished from the radical empiricism, atheism and constructivism of the French Enlightenment (Hume was viewed as too religious for Paris, while not sufficiently religious for Edinburgh). In addition to David Hume and Adam Smith, Hayek highlighted Adam Ferguson, a professor of moral philosophy at Edinburgh. Ferguson emphasized the unintended consequences of plans or actions. This has been developed by Hayek, Thomas Sowell, Walter Williams, etc. to question the intentionality of legislation and to raise the possibilities that different or opposite results may be the consequences. Hayek similarly adopted Ferguson’s concept that human institutions are the results of human action but not of human design. Successful, long-term institutions were not created from someone’s brow out of whole cloth, they were not designed; they grew or evolved from a multiplicity of human activities which had purposes, but there was not a single, intended design.

Hayek analyzed the division between those Classical Liberals in the Scottish tradition- seeing successful human institutions evolving over time and society working out solutions to problems – and those Classical Liberals in the French tradition – seeking to impose solutions devised by legislators or experts seeking immediate solutions to problems. Of course, there is no national distinction. The Scottish James Mill, and the English Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill were abstract, constructivists. Hayek admires such French Classical Liberals as Benjamin Constant and Alexis de Tocqueville.

Of course, England continued to evolve in its political and constitutional institutions during the last two centuries as during the earlier two centuries, while France’s earlier closure of representation has been in the last two centuries paralleled by its many constitutions.

Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations was published in May, 1776. Smith surrounded his economic analysis with the current crisis in England’s political economy – the threat of the loss of the American colonies (Declaration of Independence, July, 1776). Earlier (in 1756-63) England and Prussia went to war against France, Austria and Russia. Prussia was able to use internal lines to fend off the three huge land powers. England defeated France and a late ally, Spain, around the world – India, West Africa, West Indies, Quebec, and the Spanish ports of Havana and Manila. French sugar colonies were very successful and paid good prices for food supplies from English North America. During the war the prices were higher and Americans continued their sales (often through neutral Dutch ports). The English wartime government began to try to enforce the regulations and taxes which had been unenforced during the period of Salutary Neglect. This was especially so when young George III succeeded to the throne in October, 1760, and dismissed the Whig cabinet.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 11

The Seven Years’ War (1756-63) caused a massive national debt for England to pay for the massive military victories. George III and the cabinet of King’s Friends sought to tax both English and American farmers and merchants to pay for the cost of the national debt. This caused the emergence of a new Whig party – new young leaders like Edmund Burke, and different constituencies – farmers and merchants. Although Americans could not vote for parliament in London, they can be considered part of this new Whig party. In fact, when the American Revolution occurred, the Whigs in the House of Commons challenged Lord North’s government each night by sitting across from the Tory government wearing the colors of the Continental Army, buff and blue.

But, economic issues were not the only ones which featured in Classical Liberalism in the era of the American Revolution. The emergence of the King’s Friends had led to attempts at press censorship. A member of parliament, John Wilkes, published a newspaper, The North Britain from 1761, with the encouragement of his patron, Lord Temple. It opposed George III’s chief minister who was from Scotland (North Britain), who was driven from office on March 8, 1763. The North Britain attacked the King’s Speech written by the new prime minister, George Grenville, who was opposed by Grenville’s brother, Lord Temple, and brother-in-law, William Pitt, Earl of Chatham. The issue, North Britain No. 45 was published on April 23, 1763. A general warrant (which did not name who was to be arrested) was issued by the two secretaries of state. Forty-eight persons were arrested;  Wilkes was seized on April 30, 1763 and placed in the Tower of London. On May 6 Lord Chief Justice Pratt released Wilkes as his arrest was a violation of parliamentary privilege. Legal actions against the Secretary of State and the Undersecretary established the illegality of general warrants. (At the same time the issue of general warrants was being resisted in the American colonies.)  A new approach was organized by Lord Sandwich. Wilkes had left unfinished the private printing of twelve copies of an obscene parody, an ‘Essay on Woman.’ These were read aloud on November 15 in the Lords by Lord Sandwich who had been a pal of Wilkes. (Sandwich said that Wilkes would die of treason or syphilis; Wilkes responded, “It would depend, My Lord, if one embraced your politics or your mistress.”) The Commons declared No. 45 a seditious libel. One government MP had wounded Wilkes in a duel; Wilkes withdrew to Paris while he was expelled from the Commons. He was declared outlawed in court on Nov. 1, 1764.

Grenville was replaced as prime minister by the Marquis of Rockingham in the summer of 1765 after the debacle of the Stamp Tax. Pitt replaced Rockingham in 1766.

In early 1768 Wilkes returned from Paris and stood for parliament from the county of Middlesex (around London) and he was elected with a heavy majority (March 28). He was fined and imprisoned for a year each for No. 45 and the ‘Essay on Woman.’ Crowds gathered outside the prison to cheer him. On May 10 a crowd was dispersed by Scottish soldiers with bloodshed. Londoners hated the Scottish soldiers and Wilkes acquired the

Government’s instructions to the officers and published them. On February 4, 1769 Wilkes was expelled from his seat in the Commons. On February 16 he was re-elected by the Middlesex electors, and expelled. Re-elected again on March 16, he was expelled.

At the next election on April 13, Wilkes received 1143 votes to his opponent’s 296 votes.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 12

Wilkes’ re-elections were accompanied by householders in Westminster illuminating their window and popular demonstrations all around England. The Commons declared the opponent elected and seated him. Wilkes had the best Whig lawyers, and the American colonial legislatures sent money to support his defense. The expulsion of Wilkes not only showed the Americans the despotic purposes of the government regarding the press, but in England it mobilized mass electoral support for the new Whigs. Wilkes was elected Sheriff and then Lord Mayor of London (1774). He organized the City of London’s judiciary successfully to bar the arrest of printers who reported House of Commons debates (1772).

Adam Smith had close associations with parliamentary elements who supported the Americans against the government. The new Whigs feared that the King’s Friends planned a despotic regime based on extensive taxation. The English Whigs appreciated why the American Whigs wish to separate from a growing despotism in England. Adam Smith sought to show why regulation and taxation were destructive of economic growth. Smith was articulating the silent arguments which had led to the program of Salutary Neglect. He explained why low taxation and freedom from regulations had provided the foundations not only for a wider consumer demand in England and America, but also the accumulation of capital, which together were the generators of the Industrial Revolution in England. Free trade and peace became essential features of the new Whig platform at the time of the American Revolution, and the eventual Whig cabinets began to implement free trade and deregulation as the Industrial Revolution had picked up steam.

During the last quarter of the 18th century Jeremy Bentham had been writing his mathematically logical analyses of law, economics, politics. Originally a Tory, he became associated with a Scotsman, James Mill, who directed Bentham’s, and also David Ricardo’s, writings into an association with Liberalism. In economics Bentham and Ricardo were free market analysts. But, unlike the Whigs who considered political corruption, special interest legislation, etc. as violations of constitutional traditions, the Philosophical Radicals considered these faults as the result of traditions. While one part of Classical Liberalism sought the restoration of constitutional traditions, a second, the Utilitarians,  wished root and branch removal of the constitutional and legal systems.

James Mill’s son, John Stuart Mill, became the leading English Liberal intellectual. John Stuart Mill’s greatest work was On Liberty (1859). He held that government must be confined within “definite lines of demarcation,” and that its task is limited to “protection against force and fraud.” Mill held each person morally was, and legally should be, free agents, and “so long as a person practices no violence or deception, to the injury of others in person or property, he has a claim to do what he likes, without being molested or restricted by judges and legislators.”

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 13

The Philosophical Radicals were not religious. Meanwhile, the vigorous and world-renowned Liberal Party gained the leadership in England. The Liberal Party was rooted in the religious culture of England. While the great Whig family which  provided money and talent were Church of England, its voters were mainly low church, and dissenting. Also, it was supported by the Catholic Irish immigrants, especially after the Irish Famine, and was allied with the Catholic party in Irish elections to the London House of Commons. A leading French historian has proposed that England was spared ‘a French Revolution’ by the growth of Methodism among the industrial workers. Methodism was a crucial source of support for the Liberal Party. The methods of organizing and the organizers of the chapels and funds of the Methodist Church played the same role in organizing and collecting funds for the Liberal Party.

One of the great parallel organizations of the Liberals was the Anti-Corn Law League. Corn is the general word in England for grain. The Corn Law subsidized the production of grain as the population increased with economic growth and grain supplies were more cheaply available from North America, Argentina and Australia. The campaign led to the founding of The Economist to explain the economic analysis which demonstrated the consumers’ benefit from free trade, and from economic deregulation in general.

The two great leaders of Liberalism and the free trade movement were Richard Cobden and John Bright, who were members of parliament. Their campaigns to improve the lot of consumers as against the special interest legislation of producers gained increased mass support for the Liberal Party. While Cobden and Bright were not technical economists or political theorists, their writings and speeches made a profound contribution to an under- standing of economic principles and liberalism generally than the professional thinkers.

The Liberal Party strongly supported dis-establishment of the state church, and the ending of Catholics and Dissenting Protestants paying thithes to the ministers of the state church. Liberal newspapers, such as the Leeds Mercury , were strong proponents of parent based education threatened by the proposals for government education systems. Free trade and reduction of bureaucracy were Liberal Party central concerns.

But, its members were actively engaged in non-political activities of great social importance. By the early 20th century, most of England’s working families were members of voluntary social insurance programs. Many belonged to fraternal organizations – Friendly Societies – whose most important functions were insurance for unemployment, sickness and death. They also provided group medical practice. For a flat fee per year each member or family received full medical attention from a group doctor.

The English social historian, David G. Green has described 19th century English society in detail in Reinventing Civil Society: The Rediscovery of Welfare Without Politics (London, IEA Health and Welfare Unit, 1993). His chapters on “The Evolution of Mutual Aid,” “Character-Building Associations,” and “The Classical-Liberal Heyday: 1834-1911” provide detailed reports on the mutual aid that covered most of the industrial population of England. These were the non-party parts of the Liberal movement in England in the

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 14

19th century. (Similar American fraternal and friendly societies before the New Deal have been researched by Professor David Beito of the History Department, University of Alabama: David T. Beito, From Mutual Aid to the Welfare State: Fraternal Societies and Social Services, 1890-1967 (Chapel Hill, NC, University of North Carolina Press, 1999).)

Late 19th century England was graced with a number of great Liberal minds. Herbert Spencer was the most significant. Spencer carried the ideas of Liberalism to greater

intellectual heights. In Social Statics, The Principles of Ethics, and The Man Versus The State, he presented closely reasoned arguments for human liberty. The chapters of the latter can give the idea of Spencer’s thinking: “The New Toryism,” “The Coming Slavery,” “The Sins of Legislators,” “The Great Political Superstitution,” “Over-Legislation.” A quote from “Over-Legislation” (1853) will gave the flavor of Spencer’s contribution:

There is a great want of this practical humility in our political conduct. Though we

have less self-confidence than our ancestors, who did not hesitate to organize in

law their judgments on all subjects whatever, we have yet far too much. …

Though we no longer presume to coerce men for their spiritual good, we still

think ourselves called upon to coerce them for their material good: not seeing that the one is as useless and as unwarrantable as the other. Innumerable failures seem

so far, powerless to teach this. Take up a daily paper and you will probably find a

leader exposing the corruption, negligence, or mismanagement of some State-department. Cast your eye down the next column, and it is not unlikely that you will read proposals for an extension of State-supervision. …

Thus, while every day chronicles a failure, there every day reappears

the belief that it needs but an Act of Parliament and a staff of officers

to effect any end desired. Nowhere is the perennial faith of mankind

better seen. Ever since society existed Disappointment has been preaching,

“Put not you trust in legislation”; and yet the trust in legislation seems

scarcely diminished. …

 

As it is, however, they seem to have read backwards the parable of the talents.

Not to the agent of proved efficiency do they consign further duties, but to the

negligent and blundering agent. Private enterprise has done much, and done it well.

Private enterprise … has established banks, insurance societies, and the newspaper

press; has covered the sea with lines of steam-vessels, and the land with electric

telegraphs. Private enterprise has brought agriculture, manufactures, and commerce to their present height, and is now developing them with increasing rapidity. There-fore, do not trust private enterprise. On the other hand, the State so fulfils its judicial function as to ruin many, delude others, and frighten away those who most need succor; its national defences are so extravagantly and yet inefficiently administered as to call forth almost daily complaint, expostulation, or ridicule; and as the nation’s steward, it obtains from some of our vast public estates a minus revenue. Therefore, trust the State. Slight the good and faithful

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 15

servant, and promote the unprofitable one from one talent to ten. (The Man Versus The State (Indianapolis, IN, Liberty Classics, 1981), pp. 267-68, 271-72)

This approach was continued by Auberon Herbert, who especially questioned the morality of state education. (Cf. Auberon Herbert, The Right And Wrong Of Compulsion By the State (Indianapolis, IN, Liberty Classics, 1978.)

There was a large and well-thought through contribution to Classical Liberalism among the 19th century French. There was a great deal of economic analysis among the French. This was begun by Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832). Say wrote A Treatise on Political Economy (1803, revised 1814) which not only dominated French economic study, but also through its translation, dominated American economic thought during the 19th century. In contrast to the English Utilitarian economists, Malthus, Bentham, Ricardo, the Mills, who were pessimistic, Say and the French were optimistic. The French saw market economics as providing solutions to problems such as insufficient resources for growing populations.

Perhaps the most widely read and accessable of the French economists was Federic Bastiat. His Social Falacies was published in translation in 1944 by the Register Publishing Co., Santa Ana, California. Bastiat’s style was to parody and expose the general-good arguments for government intervention by the agents of special interests. Bastiat’s works were the principal source for much of President Ronald Reagan’s economic thought and policy-decisions. The central theme of Bastiat’s writings was that the market is the source of society’s harmonies, while the sophisms of special interest legislation introduce discord and injustice in society. Bastiat’s emphasis on the harmony of the market is a continuation of the 17th century theme of the civilizing role of commerce.

Based upon economic theory, Benjamin Constant and Alexis de Tocqueville expanded the Classical Liberal analysis into social institutions and constitutionalism. Constant stood strongly for strict adherence to constitutonalism and to bills of rights.He was a strong proponent of freedom of the press. He had challenged the persistence of classical models where the polis or the state was the expression of liberty, not the individual. Constant showed that during the middle ages that perspective had been replaced totally by the concept of liberty of the individual.

Constant himself had engaged in much historical research. But, French Classical Liberals initiated a complete study European history in the middle ages to find the explanations for the ideas and the institutions of liberty. The most important of the Classical Liberal historians was AugustinThierry. He sought the manuscript charters which medieval merchants had won from rulers, and arranged for their preservation and publication. This autonomy and fiscal self-control permitted the accumulation of capital and investment in new enterprises which expanded both the wealth and freedom of the inhabitants.

Classical Liberalism – Liggio – page 16

Constant’s emphasis on bills of rights led directly to his writing on freedom of the press.

Classical Liberals were not only the significant writers on the philosophy of freedom of the press but also they were in the forefront of the defense of freedom of the press. Among the examples was the son-in-law of J.-B. Say, Charles Comte. Comte and his partner Charles Dunoyer sought to avoid the censorship authority of the government by publishing periodicals of more than 360 pages – the upper limit set for censorship. Nevertheless, the government objected to their articles and sought to apprehend Comte. His wife pulled the china closet onto the police while Comte escaped and fled to Switzerland (the French pressured the Vaud canton and Comte ended in London until the 1830 July Revolution). Dunoyer was taken to a remote province to seek a guilty verdict; but the local population rallied to the Liberal intellectual and undermined the government’s purpose. Classical Liberals centered on freedom of the press until their success in the 1830 July Revolution.

Even more in centralized France, Classical Liberals struggled for parents’ rights to educate their children without the control of the government.  Charles de Montalembert was the most important advocate in France of freedom of education from the state. After freedom of the press was gained, freedom of education from the state became a focus of struggle. Just as the state should not control knowledge through control of the press, the state should not control knowledge through control of education. The government’s ideal of newspapers owned and published by the state was equally objectionable as government ownership of schools and control over the selection of textbooks.

Alexis de Tocqueville sought to show the continuity of state institutions through successive revolutions. Despite changes in the forms of government and the constitutions,